Inflation, deflation, and capacity utilization

126문장 0% 일본어 번역 0명 참여 출처 : 칸아카데미

Inflation, deflation, and capacity utilization

With all the talk of the deficits that we're entering, and the stimulus bill, and all the money that's being spent on the bank bailouts, and potentially the auto bailouts, the question that everyone's asking: Is this going to lead to inflation?

And that is what I hope to address in this video.

And I guess a good starting point is, well, what is inflation?

It's a general increase in the prices of goods and services.

So they actually measure it by - they take a basket of goods and services and they see how those prices compare to a reference year.

And if those prices go up by 3%, they might use a consumer price index.

They'll say inflation increased by 3%. So that's what's inflation.

And the opposite of inflation, if things actually get cheaper, is deflation.

If one year 10 megabytes of RAM costs x dollars, and then the next year, it costs a little bit less, it's actually a deflationary process, at least in that market.

So without the those definitions out of the way, let's talk a little bit about what causes it.

A couple of days ago, I made these videos on cupcake economics, where I talked about what happens when the cupcake factories have high utilization or low utilization.

What might happen with prices?

And the reason why I did that is because I really want to make it very clear that it really is utilization of factories or of people that drive prices.

Let's say this is all the capacity that I have.

When I talk about capacity in this video, I'm speaking in very general terms.

It's all of the goods and services that we could produce.

We could just talk about labor capacity, and then unemployment rate is a measure of what is essentially not being utilized.

But this is just our capacity, our productive capacity.

And in those cupcake economics videos, I showed that if the demand is pushing up against capacity. let me do demand in a different color.

If demand is really close to capacity - and I know everything I draw kind of looks like balance sheets, but this isn't intended to be a balance sheet.

This is intended just to show you that demand is pushing up against capacity.

So in this situation, let's say, this is capacity.

If demand is at 90% of capacity, then the people with the capacity might say, gee,

instead of trying to just try to sell that extra unit - this is demand - instead of just trying to sell that extra unit and have to worry about all the raw materials and have to work for that extra unit,

why don't I just raise prices, right?

So high utilization of capacity, it leads to prices increasing.

And this isn't some kind of fancy macroeconomic principal; it's true if you're running a lemonade stand.

If all of a sudden, you're starting to sell 95% of your lemonade, you'll probably say, hey, maybe it's worth it if I raise the price.

On the other hand, low utilization - let me pick another color --will lead the prices dropping.

And you go back to your lemonade stand, and you say, wow, if I'm only selling 20% of the lemonade that I make, maybe my problem is that my lemonade's too expensive.

And frankly, if there was a bunch of lemonade stands, everyone is trying to sell their capacity.

So just to compete with each other, they'll all lower prices.

Actually, I'll throw another thing in here that's a little unrelated to inflation, but high utilization makes prices go up and it also makes people want to add more capacity, right?

So also investment goes up.

Both of those things do add more capacity, but we won't worry about that right now.

So if you accept that - and I think it's a reasonable argument, because it's really based on common sense things --then I think you'll buy the argument that, if you have very low utilization, it's difficult to have inflation.

And, likewise, if you have very high utilization, it's hard to avoid inflation.

And to kind of hit the point home, actually, I took our company's Bloomberg terminal and copied and pasted these charts here.

And the orange - and I know you can't see it that well on YouTube , so I'll try to make it clear in my drawing,

But this orange I'll do it the same color, --this orange shows capacity utilization, and the starting date right here, I think it was 1967.

This is 1969, actually December 31, 1969, so this is 1970, beginning of 1970, this is beginning of 1980, beginning of 1990, this is 2000.

This orange line represents capacity utilization.

So up here this is 90% utilization and then down here this is 70% utilization.

So if we look here, in the late 60's, we have very high utilization.

Arguably because of the Vietnam War, we had factories running at capacity to build bombs and Agent Orange and God knows what else.

And then utilization went down.

We could talk a lot about the history, but, in general, the interesting thing - well, actually, before I go into what happened, let's think about what this white line is.

So the orange line is utilization.

Up here we had like 90% utilization.

Very recently, this was like 2007, we had 80%, and very recently, utilization has dropped off, which essentially just means we're not running our factories at full tilt.

This white line is year-over-year inflation growth, and let me do that in white.

This is year-over-year inflation growth.

Actually, let me draw a zero line, so you can separate inflation from deflation.

Let me see, zero inflation is right over here.

That's zero inflation.

And you see, in the time series that I've done, we've never had zero inflation, although we have had periods of a very high inflation.

But the interesting thing, just falling into the cupcake economics and this whole notion of capacity utilization, is that inflationary periods are always preceded, at least all the data I have, by increases in capacity utilization.

So you could view this as the beginning of a pretty significant uptick in prices, right?

And notice, it was preceded by an uptick in capacity utilization.

So, if you saw right here, wow, capacity utilization is starting to go up - and actually, another interesting thing is to see what threshold of utilization starts to trigger inflation.

So over here, you say,

OK, when inflation really started turning around, we were at a capacity utilization of roughly 83%, 84% right there.

And then, if you look at the next period where inflation really started to hit - you can either pick that point or that point --where was capacity utilization?

It was around that same level that was right there.

It was above 80.

This was about 82%.

And we could pick every period before that.

Well, since then, inflation really hasn't been a major problem.

These are our two major bouts of inflation, in the early 70's and in the early 80's, and those were when we had extremely high capacity utilization.

So the point I want to make here is capacity utilization really is the driver of inflation.

You actually could find it the other way around.

So this white line here, you don't see it because the orange line - actually, I realize that I'm showing you off the screen.

Let me actually reduce my window, so I can show you.

So this is more recent, where we see that capacity utilization started falling off.

I think this is in the summer of 2007.

And you don't see it there because it's overwritten, but the inflation line has also dropped considerably.

It comes down to here.

But notice once again, although here it's pretty close, but utilization dropped off a couple of quarters before inflation dropped off.

And that's why I always wonder why the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, they always talk about different inflation indicators and what to do about interest rates, when you do have a pretty good indicator, and that's capacity utilization.

The next question that everyone has is, OK fine, Sal.

Capacity utilization drives inflation.

We can all buy that.

But clearly, what's going on right now is just a wholesale printing of money.

And won't the wholesale printing of money drive demand to go up, and then we'll have very high capacity utilization, and then we'll have inflation or even hyper-inflation?

And my argument there is that's normally the case.

Normally, if you increase the money supply, if the money supply goes up, that should increase demand.

But there's a subtle, and it's almost a philosophical point, but it's an important one, to realize: Money just allows you to express demand.

Let's say I really, really want to buy a Rolls Royce, I just don't have the money.

If someone gave me $200,000 into my pocket, then I could express that demand to buy the Rolls Royce.

On the other hand, let's say, I have everything I need.

I'm happy with my Honda and my two-bedroom apartment, and someone gave me $200,000.

So they've increased, at least, my money supply.

Will that increase the demand for the Rolls Royce? No.

I have money to express the demand, but I won't do it, because I don't think it's necessary.

So you can make that same analogy in the economy as a whole, where you can imagine an island where, let's say, there's five of us or three of us, because I don't want to draw five people.

And between us, we use seashells as a currency.

And we're very confident.

And maybe I'm the builder, and this guy's the fisherman, and she's the farmer.

Let's say in one year I use a seashell to get some fish.

And then he uses that seashell to buy some crops.

Then she uses that seashell to buy a house.

And I use that seashell again to buy more fish.

You can see that one seashell, even though my money supply on that island is one seashell, it can transact many times in that year.

So the velocity in this example is very high.

So you notice that my expression of demand happens in these actual transactions.

I'll do a classical money supply equation soon.

But you could imagine another reality, where, for some reason, I stop trusting this guy.

I've become very cautious, and I say, well, you know what?

I don't want to give him my seashell, because I'm not sure if I'm going to get that seashell back again to do something else.

So you can imagine a reality where the central bank of our island, all of a sudden, they find hundreds of seashells.

And they put seashells in everyone's pockets so we're all full of seashells.

But all of us have lost so much confidence in the economy, or are so unsure over whether other people are going to use my goods and services, that I don't want to use their goods and services.

So we all just start hoarding seashells.

So this is a situation where the money supply could actually increase pretty substantially, but since no one wants to express it through demand, it's not going to increase utilization.

And so in the situation that we're in right now, if you're wondering about whether you're going to see inflation or deflation, my argument is look at capacity utilization.

People can point to the money supply.

This is a classic money supply equation.

The money supply times the velocity of money - that's how often the actual dollars switch hands - is equal to the price of the average price of goods times the total quantity of goods and services we have.

So most people say, wow, if the money supply increases, then won't prices increase?

Well, that would be true if you assume that velocity and quantity are constant.

But we're saying that whenever you have major shocks and people lose confidence, this velocity can slow down considerably, especially when things like financial intermediaries start hoarding money and people start putting money into their mattresses.

In fact, often times, people don't even consider things that aren't being transacted money.

For example, those commemorative coins that they sell on TV.

They're not considered part of the money supply, because people don't use them as money.

Anyway, I'm all out of time. I'll continue this discussion in the next video.

번역 0%

Inflation, deflation, and capacity utilization발음듣기

With all the talk of the deficits that we're entering, and the stimulus bill, and all the money that's being spent on the bank bailouts, and potentially the auto bailouts, the question that everyone's asking: Is this going to lead to inflation?발음듣기

And that is what I hope to address in this video.발음듣기

And I guess a good starting point is, well, what is inflation?발음듣기

It's a general increase in the prices of goods and services.발음듣기

So they actually measure it by - they take a basket of goods and services and they see how those prices compare to a reference year.발음듣기

And if those prices go up by 3%, they might use a consumer price index.발음듣기

They'll say inflation increased by 3%. So that's what's inflation.발음듣기

And the opposite of inflation, if things actually get cheaper, is deflation.발음듣기

If one year 10 megabytes of RAM costs x dollars, and then the next year, it costs a little bit less, it's actually a deflationary process, at least in that market.발음듣기

So without the those definitions out of the way, let's talk a little bit about what causes it.발음듣기

A couple of days ago, I made these videos on cupcake economics, where I talked about what happens when the cupcake factories have high utilization or low utilization.발음듣기

What might happen with prices?발음듣기

And the reason why I did that is because I really want to make it very clear that it really is utilization of factories or of people that drive prices.발음듣기

Let's say this is all the capacity that I have.발음듣기

When I talk about capacity in this video, I'm speaking in very general terms.발음듣기

It's all of the goods and services that we could produce.발음듣기

We could just talk about labor capacity, and then unemployment rate is a measure of what is essentially not being utilized.발음듣기

But this is just our capacity, our productive capacity.발음듣기

And in those cupcake economics videos, I showed that if the demand is pushing up against capacity. let me do demand in a different color.발음듣기

If demand is really close to capacity - and I know everything I draw kind of looks like balance sheets, but this isn't intended to be a balance sheet.발음듣기

This is intended just to show you that demand is pushing up against capacity.발음듣기

So in this situation, let's say, this is capacity.발음듣기

If demand is at 90% of capacity, then the people with the capacity might say, gee,발음듣기

instead of trying to just try to sell that extra unit - this is demand - instead of just trying to sell that extra unit and have to worry about all the raw materials and have to work for that extra unit,발음듣기

why don't I just raise prices, right?발음듣기

So high utilization of capacity, it leads to prices increasing.발음듣기

And this isn't some kind of fancy macroeconomic principal; it's true if you're running a lemonade stand.발음듣기

If all of a sudden, you're starting to sell 95% of your lemonade, you'll probably say, hey, maybe it's worth it if I raise the price.발음듣기

On the other hand, low utilization - let me pick another color --will lead the prices dropping.발음듣기

And you go back to your lemonade stand, and you say, wow, if I'm only selling 20% of the lemonade that I make, maybe my problem is that my lemonade's too expensive.발음듣기

And frankly, if there was a bunch of lemonade stands, everyone is trying to sell their capacity.발음듣기

So just to compete with each other, they'll all lower prices.발음듣기

Actually, I'll throw another thing in here that's a little unrelated to inflation, but high utilization makes prices go up and it also makes people want to add more capacity, right?발음듣기

So also investment goes up.발음듣기

Both of those things do add more capacity, but we won't worry about that right now.발음듣기

So if you accept that - and I think it's a reasonable argument, because it's really based on common sense things --then I think you'll buy the argument that, if you have very low utilization, it's difficult to have inflation.발음듣기

And, likewise, if you have very high utilization, it's hard to avoid inflation.발음듣기

And to kind of hit the point home, actually, I took our company's Bloomberg terminal and copied and pasted these charts here.발음듣기

And the orange - and I know you can't see it that well on YouTube , so I'll try to make it clear in my drawing,발음듣기

But this orange I'll do it the same color, --this orange shows capacity utilization, and the starting date right here, I think it was 1967.발음듣기

This is 1969, actually December 31, 1969, so this is 1970, beginning of 1970, this is beginning of 1980, beginning of 1990, this is 2000.발음듣기

This orange line represents capacity utilization.발음듣기

So up here this is 90% utilization and then down here this is 70% utilization.발음듣기

So if we look here, in the late 60's, we have very high utilization.발음듣기

Arguably because of the Vietnam War, we had factories running at capacity to build bombs and Agent Orange and God knows what else.발음듣기

And then utilization went down.발음듣기

We could talk a lot about the history, but, in general, the interesting thing - well, actually, before I go into what happened, let's think about what this white line is.발음듣기

So the orange line is utilization.발음듣기

Up here we had like 90% utilization.발음듣기

Very recently, this was like 2007, we had 80%, and very recently, utilization has dropped off, which essentially just means we're not running our factories at full tilt.발음듣기

This white line is year-over-year inflation growth, and let me do that in white.발음듣기

This is year-over-year inflation growth.발음듣기

Actually, let me draw a zero line, so you can separate inflation from deflation.발음듣기

Let me see, zero inflation is right over here.발음듣기

That's zero inflation.발음듣기

And you see, in the time series that I've done, we've never had zero inflation, although we have had periods of a very high inflation.발음듣기

But the interesting thing, just falling into the cupcake economics and this whole notion of capacity utilization, is that inflationary periods are always preceded, at least all the data I have, by increases in capacity utilization.발음듣기

So you could view this as the beginning of a pretty significant uptick in prices, right?발음듣기

And notice, it was preceded by an uptick in capacity utilization.발음듣기

So, if you saw right here, wow, capacity utilization is starting to go up - and actually, another interesting thing is to see what threshold of utilization starts to trigger inflation.발음듣기

So over here, you say,발음듣기

OK, when inflation really started turning around, we were at a capacity utilization of roughly 83%, 84% right there.발음듣기

And then, if you look at the next period where inflation really started to hit - you can either pick that point or that point --where was capacity utilization?발음듣기

It was around that same level that was right there.발음듣기

It was above 80.발음듣기

This was about 82%.발음듣기

And we could pick every period before that.발음듣기

Well, since then, inflation really hasn't been a major problem.발음듣기

These are our two major bouts of inflation, in the early 70's and in the early 80's, and those were when we had extremely high capacity utilization.발음듣기

So the point I want to make here is capacity utilization really is the driver of inflation.발음듣기

You actually could find it the other way around.발음듣기

So this white line here, you don't see it because the orange line - actually, I realize that I'm showing you off the screen.발음듣기

Let me actually reduce my window, so I can show you.발음듣기

So this is more recent, where we see that capacity utilization started falling off.발음듣기

I think this is in the summer of 2007.발음듣기

And you don't see it there because it's overwritten, but the inflation line has also dropped considerably.발음듣기

It comes down to here.발음듣기

But notice once again, although here it's pretty close, but utilization dropped off a couple of quarters before inflation dropped off.발음듣기

And that's why I always wonder why the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, they always talk about different inflation indicators and what to do about interest rates, when you do have a pretty good indicator, and that's capacity utilization.발음듣기

The next question that everyone has is, OK fine, Sal.발음듣기

Capacity utilization drives inflation.발음듣기

We can all buy that.발음듣기

But clearly, what's going on right now is just a wholesale printing of money.발음듣기

And won't the wholesale printing of money drive demand to go up, and then we'll have very high capacity utilization, and then we'll have inflation or even hyper-inflation?발음듣기

And my argument there is that's normally the case.발음듣기

Normally, if you increase the money supply, if the money supply goes up, that should increase demand.발음듣기

But there's a subtle, and it's almost a philosophical point, but it's an important one, to realize: Money just allows you to express demand.발음듣기

Let's say I really, really want to buy a Rolls Royce, I just don't have the money.발음듣기

If someone gave me $200,000 into my pocket, then I could express that demand to buy the Rolls Royce.발음듣기

On the other hand, let's say, I have everything I need.발음듣기

I'm happy with my Honda and my two-bedroom apartment, and someone gave me $200,000.발음듣기

So they've increased, at least, my money supply.발음듣기

Will that increase the demand for the Rolls Royce? No.발음듣기

I have money to express the demand, but I won't do it, because I don't think it's necessary.발음듣기

So you can make that same analogy in the economy as a whole, where you can imagine an island where, let's say, there's five of us or three of us, because I don't want to draw five people.발음듣기

And between us, we use seashells as a currency.발음듣기

And we're very confident.발음듣기

And maybe I'm the builder, and this guy's the fisherman, and she's the farmer.발음듣기

Let's say in one year I use a seashell to get some fish.발음듣기

And then he uses that seashell to buy some crops.발음듣기

Then she uses that seashell to buy a house.발음듣기

And I use that seashell again to buy more fish.발음듣기

You can see that one seashell, even though my money supply on that island is one seashell, it can transact many times in that year.발음듣기

So the velocity in this example is very high.발음듣기

So you notice that my expression of demand happens in these actual transactions.발음듣기

I'll do a classical money supply equation soon.발음듣기

But you could imagine another reality, where, for some reason, I stop trusting this guy.발음듣기

I've become very cautious, and I say, well, you know what?발음듣기

I don't want to give him my seashell, because I'm not sure if I'm going to get that seashell back again to do something else.발음듣기

So you can imagine a reality where the central bank of our island, all of a sudden, they find hundreds of seashells.발음듣기

And they put seashells in everyone's pockets so we're all full of seashells.발음듣기

But all of us have lost so much confidence in the economy, or are so unsure over whether other people are going to use my goods and services, that I don't want to use their goods and services.발음듣기

So we all just start hoarding seashells.발음듣기

So this is a situation where the money supply could actually increase pretty substantially, but since no one wants to express it through demand, it's not going to increase utilization.발음듣기

And so in the situation that we're in right now, if you're wondering about whether you're going to see inflation or deflation, my argument is look at capacity utilization.발음듣기

People can point to the money supply.발음듣기

This is a classic money supply equation.발음듣기

The money supply times the velocity of money - that's how often the actual dollars switch hands - is equal to the price of the average price of goods times the total quantity of goods and services we have.발음듣기

So most people say, wow, if the money supply increases, then won't prices increase?발음듣기

Well, that would be true if you assume that velocity and quantity are constant.발음듣기

But we're saying that whenever you have major shocks and people lose confidence, this velocity can slow down considerably, especially when things like financial intermediaries start hoarding money and people start putting money into their mattresses.발음듣기

In fact, often times, people don't even consider things that aren't being transacted money.발음듣기

For example, those commemorative coins that they sell on TV.발음듣기

They're not considered part of the money supply, because people don't use them as money.발음듣기

Anyway, I'm all out of time. I'll continue this discussion in the next video.발음듣기

Top